ТОП просматриваемых книг сайта:
Toppling Foreign Governments. Melissa Willard-Foster
Читать онлайн.Название Toppling Foreign Governments
Год выпуска 0
isbn 9780812296785
Автор произведения Melissa Willard-Foster
Издательство Ingram
Opposition to the leader can also be latent. In these instances, widespread opposition may exist, but the majority of the population is too intimidated to organize and fight. Foreign powers may have to contribute greater military aid to mobilize latent opposition, but they may still judge the costs of regime change as low because the population is unlikely to rally to the leader’s defense. Foreign powers may also anticipate (rightly or wrongly) that their invasions will inspire the latent opposition to fight. Uganda’s Idi Amin faced latent opposition as a result of his regime’s brutality. When Tanzanian troops invaded in 1978 to topple Amin, liberated civilians, encouraged by the arrival of foreign forces, joined the fight.46 Unpopular leaders may also attempt to ward off coups by conducting purges that strip the military of its talent and resources. This may leave the military unable to fend off a foreign invader and thereby lower the foreign power’s anticipated costs of an invasion. Amin’s purges and abuses had led to such low morale among Ugandan troops that many were reportedly more interested in looting or fleeing than fighting off the Tanzanian invasion.47
The stronger state can also use dissident groups to reassure the target population that it does not have imperial designs. When Vietnam invaded Cambodia in 1978, it sought to assuage long-standing Cambodian fears of Vietnamese domination by cobbling together the Kampuchean United Front for National Salvation (KUFNS) from pro-Hanoi Communists and Khmer Rouge defectors. Although the KUFNS’s military contribution was small, Vietnamese leaders saw the group as a way to win broad Cambodian support.48 The foreign power may also reduce its diplomatic and reputational costs by using domestic opposition groups to legitimize its regime-change operation to an international audience. Tanzanian president Julius Nyerere, for example, looked to dodge international criticism of Tanzania’s invasion of Uganda by using exiles to take control of Kampala.49
Foreign powers may also use indirect or covert force to avoid the military and political costs of direct military force. They may, for example, use economic pressure or covert propaganda campaigns to weaken the leader politically and encourage a coup; or, they may supply rebels with military aid, assistance, and training. In 1949, President Harry Truman’s administration attempted to overthrow the Communist government of Albania by covertly training, funding, and transporting Albanian exiles and Albanian Americans to that country’s shores.50 In 1957, the Eisenhower administration began covertly funding Indonesian rebels to take down President Sukarno, whose government it feared would fall prey to communist influence.51
Foreign powers can also avoid using direct military force by encouraging the internal opposition, which operates within the government, to undertake a coup. The internal opposition has access to military and political power, which it can use to oust the leader. The United States, for example, overthrew the Iranian prime minister, Mohammad Mosaddeq, in 1953 without the use of military force. Foreign economic pressure and domestic political violence had sapped Mosaddeq’s once strong domestic support. With his political position weakened, the CIA was able to orchestrate a coup by organizing protests, bribing high-ranking army officials, and pressuring Mohammad Reza Shah to collaborate.52 External opposition groups that manage to gain influence may also be able to launch coups. The Communist Party of Czechoslovakia, for example, acquired control over the army, police, and key ministries after performing well in the 1946 elections. When it began losing support in 1948, Moscow urged the party to orchestrate a takeover by purging noncommunists from the security forces and ministries under its control. When noncommunist government ministers resigned in protest, the party staged demonstrations. Fearing the Soviets would use the unrest as a pretext for intervention, the noncommunist president, Edvard Beneš, ceded to the communists’ demands, allowing for their complete takeover.53
In some instances, foreign powers may accomplish regime change simply by convincing the target state’s military not to fight. In 1909, for example, the United States supported Nicaraguan rebels in their attempt to overthrow the populist president José Santos Zelaya. When the rebels proved unable to defeat the Nicaraguan army, the United States stationed marines between the two sides, supposedly as a neutral force to protect Americans. The US commander then forbade the Nicaraguan army from firing in the direction of the rebels. The Nicaraguan army stood by, helpless, as the United States continued supplying the rebels with weapons and funds.54 Once Zelaya realized a military victory was impossible, he offered to step down.
Over the long term, opposition groups with either popular support or military capabilities may also require less foreign aid to survive if they do attain power. When the opposition has a large following, the population is less likely to question its right to rule, which may spare the foreign power from having to help prop it up. This is often the case when foreign powers reinstall popularly supported governments, much as the Allies did in Nazi-occupied countries following World War II. Alternatively, when opposition groups lack a large following but possess significant military capabilities, they often use those capabilities to eliminate their opponents. In Chile, for example, the United States helped facilitate a military coup in 1973, after which the military used its monopoly on the use of force to violently suppress dissent.55
In choosing regime change, the foreign power must also consider whether the opposition shares its policy preferences. This requirement, however, is often easily met, as opposition groups may willingly compromise their policy positions to attain foreign assistance in securing power. As long as the opposition is at least marginally closer than the leader to the foreign power’s policy preferences, the foreign power will expend fewer resources coaxing the opposition to cooperate than it would the leader. In many instances, the external opposition already shares some of the foreign power’s policy preferences. But even when the external opposition is more opposed to the foreign power than the leader, or too weak to fight, the foreign power can often coerce or induce the leader’s internal rivals into trading policy concessions for help in attaining power. In the next chapter, I explain in more detail when the foreign power is likely to find willing collaborators among the external and/or internal opposition. I also explain how the relative strength of these two groups affects the type of regime change the foreign power imposes.
In all, as long as a foreign power can locate strong and marginally sympathetic opposition groups, it is more likely to estimate the costs of regime change as low. That the very element causing a leader to appear susceptible to overthrow—domestic opposition—is also the very element causing the leader to resist is what tempts foreign powers to use regime change to resolve disputes with recalcitrant foreign leaders. Domestic opposition makes the leader appear more costly to coerce but also cheaper to overthrow. Leaders without opposition will not necessarily be more conciliatory. Though their domestic compliance costs are lower, their concessions will still depend on how vulnerable they are to military and economic pressure. But when compared to leaders with similar resources, domestically strong leaders will make greater concessions than their domestically vulnerable counterparts.56 Among leaders facing domestic opposition, greater military vulnerability should also increase the likelihood of FIRC. Although states have been known to attempt regime change in their peer competitors, large disparities of military power should lower the expected costs of FIRC, making its use more likely. All told, my argument suggests the following three hypotheses:
H1a1: When states’ interests diverge, the stronger one side’s internal or external opposition is, the greater the probability that the opposing side will pursue FIRC.
H1a2: The greater the military vulnerability of one state in a dispute, the more likely it is that the stronger state will attempt regime change when the weaker state’s leader faces domestic opposition.
H1b1: All else equal, targeted leaders without domestic opposition will make more concessions than those with opposition.
The Effect of Major Events and Crises
Major events and crises can serve as catalysts for regime change. They can affect the timing of the foreign power’s policy decision to impose regime change by prompting policymakers to reassess their policy options and change course. They can also influence how policymakers estimate the costs of using military force. A crisis involving a military confrontation with