ТОП просматриваемых книг сайта:
Rough Ways Made Smooth. Richard Anthony Proctor
Читать онлайн.Название Rough Ways Made Smooth
Год выпуска 0
isbn 4064066200206
Автор произведения Richard Anthony Proctor
Жанр Математика
Издательство Bookwire
It appears again that certain meteorological phenomena show a tendency, more or less marked, to run through a ten-year cycle. Thus, from the records of rainfall kept at Oxford it appears that more rain fell under west and south-west winds when sun-spots were largest and most numerous than under south and south-east winds, these last being the more rainy winds when sun-spots were least in size and fewest in number. This is a somewhat recondite relation, and at least proves that earnest search has been made for such cyclic relations as we are considering. But this is not all. When other records were examined, the striking circumstance was discovered that elsewhere, as at St. Petersburg, the state of things observed at Oxford was precisely reversed. At some intermediate point between Oxford and St. Petersburg, no doubt the rainfall under the winds named was equally distributed throughout the spot period. Moreover, as the conditions thus differ at different places, we may assume that they differ also at different times. Such relations appear then to be not only recondite, but complicated.
When we learn that during nearly two entire sun-spot periods cyclones have been somewhat more numerous in the Indian Seas when spots are most numerous than when the sun is without spots, and vice versâ, we recognise the possible existence of cyclic relations better worth knowing than those heretofore mentioned. The evidence is not absolutely decisive; some, indeed, regard it as scarcely trustworthy. Yet there does seem to have been an excess of cyclonic disturbance during the last two periods of great solar disturbance, precisely as there was also an excess of magnetic disturbance during those periods. The excess was scarcely sufficient, however, to justify the rather daring statement made by one observer, that 'the whole question of cyclones is merely a question of solar activity.' We had records of some very remarkable cyclonic disturbances during the years 1876 and 1877, when the sun showed very few spots, the actual minimum of disturbance having probably been reached late in 1877. A prediction that 1877 would be a year of few and slight storms would have proved disastrous if implicit reliance had been placed on it by seamen and travellers.
Rainfall and atmospheric pressure in India have been found to vary in a cyclic manner, of late years at any rate, the periods being generally about 10 or 11 years. The activity of the sun, as shown by the existence of many spots, apparently makes more rainfall at Madras, Najpore, and some other places; while at Calcutta, Bombay, Mysore, and elsewhere it produces a contrary effect. Yet these effects are produced in a somewhat capricious way: for sometimes the year of actual maximum spot frequency is one in which rainfall is below the average (instead of above) at the former stations, and above the average (instead of below) at the latter. It is only by taking averages—and in a somewhat artificial manner—that the relation seems to be indicated on which stress has been laid.
Since Indian famines are directly dependent on defective rainfall, it is natural that during the years over which observation has hitherto extended the connection apparently existing between sun-spots and Indian rainfall should seem also to extend itself to Indian famines. It was equally to be expected that since cyclones have been rather more numerous, for some time past, in years when sun-spots have been most numerous, shipwrecks should also have been somewhat more frequent in such years. Two years ago Mr. Jeula gave some evidence which, in his opinion, indicated such a connection between sun-spots and shipwrecks. He showed that in the four years of fewest spots the mean percentage of losses was 8.64; in four intermediate years the mean percentage was 9.21; in three remaining years of the eleven-year cycle—that is, in three years of greatest spot frequency the mean percentage was 9.53. Some suggested that possibly such events as the American war, which included two of the three years of greatest spot frequency, may have had more effect than sun-spots in increasing the percentage of ships lost; while perhaps, the depression following the commercial panic of 1866 (at a time of fewest sun-spots) may have been almost as effective in reducing the percentage of losses as the diminished area of solar maculation. But others consider that we ought rather to regard the American war as yet another product of the sun's increased activity in 1860–61, and the great commercial panic of 1866 as directly resulting from diminished sun-spots at that time, thus obtaining fresh evidence of the sun's specific influence on terrestrial phenomena instead of explaining away the evidence derived from Lloyd's list of losses.
This leads us to the last, and, in some respects, the most singular suggestion respecting solar influence on mundane events—the idea, namely, that commercial crises synchronise with the sun-spot period, occurring near the time when spots are least in size and fewest in number; or, as Professor Jevons (to whom the definite enunciation of this theory is due) poetically presents the matter, that from 'the sun, which is truly "of this great world both eye and soul," we derive our strength and our weakness, our success and our failure, our elation in commercial mania, and our despondency and ruin in commercial collapse.' We have better opportunities of dealing with this theory than with the others, for we have records of commercial matters extending as far back as the beginning of the eighteenth century. In fact, we have better evidence than Professor Jevons seems to have supposed, for whereas in his discussion of the matter he considers only the probable average of the sun-spot period, we know approximately the epochs themselves at which the maxima and minima of sun spots have occurred since the year 1700. The evidence as presented by Professor Jevons is very striking, though when examined in detail it is rather disappointing. He presents the whole series of decennial crises as follows:—1701? (such query marks are his own), 1711, 1721, 1731–32, 1742 (?), 1752 (?), 1763, 1772–73, 1783, 1793, 1804–5 (?), 1815, 1825, 1836–9 (1837 in the United States), 1847, 1857, 1866 and 1878. The average interval comes out 10.466 years, showing, as Jevons points out, 'almost perfect coincidence with Brown's estimate of the average sun-spot period.' Let us see, however, whether these dates correspond so closely with the years of minimum spot-frequency as to remove all doubt. Taking 5¼ years as the average interval between maximum and minimum sun-spot frequency, we should like to find every crisis occurring within a year or so on either side of the minimum though we should prefer perhaps to find the crisis always following the time of fewest sun-spots, as this would more directly show the depressing effect of a spotless sun. No crisis ought to occur within a year or so of maximum solar disturbance; for that, it should seem, would be fatal to the suggested theory. Taking the commercial crises in order, and comparing them with the known (or approximately known) epochs of maximum and minimum spot frequency, we obtain the following results (we italicize numbers or results unfavourable to the theory):—The doubtful crisis of 1701 followed a spot minimum by three years; the crisis of 1711 preceded a minimum by one year; that of 1721 preceded a minimum by two years; 1731–32, preceded a minimum by one year; 1742 preceded a minimum by three years; 1752 followed a maximum by two years; 1763 followed a maximum by a year and a half; 1772–73 came midway between a maximum and a minimum; 1783 preceded a minimum by nearly two years; 1793 came nearly midway between a maximum and a minimum; 1804–5 coincided with a maximum; 1815 preceded a maximum by two years; 1825 followed a minimum by two years; 1836–39 included the year 1837 of maximum solar activity (that year being the time also when a commercial crisis occurred in the United States); 1847 preceded a maximum by a year and a half; 1866 preceded a minimum by a year; and 1878 followed a minimum by a year. Four favourable cases out of 17 can hardly be considered convincing. If we include cases lying within two years of a minimum, the favourable cases mount up to seven, leaving ten unfavourable ones. It must be remembered, too, that a single decidedly unfavourable case (as 1804, 1815, 1837) does more to disprove such a theory than 20 favourable