Скачать книгу

reforms of industrial and trade policy, opening them up, even if only a little. We noted earlier the implications of the softening of import restrictions for the price of capital equipment for Indian investors. The consequence of changing political attitudes, of the advent of new business elites, and of the reforms that were implemented, was that by the late 1980s the deals environment had become both more ordered and more open, and this is seen by Kar and Sen as having been ‘the crucial enabling factor behind the increase in private investment in equipment’ (2016: 41).

      These arguments are not universally accepted. Arvind Panagariya, whose analysis of phases of growth we referred to earlier (see table 2.3) argued that only in the three years from 1988–89 to 1990–91 was there a distinctively higher growth rate, and that this was the fruit of the modest, piecemeal reforms that had been pursued to that time. The real break in the growth trend came only with more thorough-going market-friendly reforms that were launched in 1991 (Panagariya 2008). Panagariya, and others too, also thought that the growth of the 1980s depended upon unsustainable fiscal expansion. Large fiscal deficits were run up, government debt expanded hugely through the decade, exerting a big stimulus to demand – but in a way that was held to be unsustainable. Kotwal et al. (2011), from their review of these arguments and the evidence for them, reach the judicious conclusion that all of the factors that are referred to may have played a part. None of the other explanations, however, addresses the crucial question of how the settlement between business and political elites changed. The more ordered deals environment that Kar and Sen discern in the 1980s was then extended in the 1990s.

      The particular moment that made for a tipping point was that of the economic crisis that confronted the Rao government as it came into office. The immediate cause of the crisis was an abrupt fall in remittances, and oil price increases that were brought about by the Gulf War of 1990–91, but it was underlain by the deficit that followed from the expansionary fiscal policies that had been pursued by Rajiv Gandhi’s government, a widening current account deficit, and mounting external indebtedness. By the early summer of 1991, India had sufficient reserves to pay for only two weeks’ worth of imports. There certainly was a liquidity crisis, but it might have been tackled without embarking on structural reform. That it was ‘the harbinger of a significant structural adjustment-cum-liberalization reform’ (Kar and Sen 2016: 46), was the result of the persuasion of the international financial institutions and of the economic liberals in the Indian establishment, in a wider context in which neo-liberalism had become intellectually dominant (Harvey 2005). By 1991, it was widely thought by economists that the Indian economy was in urgent need of further and more radical reform. Even Rodrik and Subramanian (2005), though they thought that the growth surge that revived the Indian economy after 1991–92 was powered very substantially by the productivity growth and manufacturing base put in place in the 1980s, recognized that further reforms were necessary.

      In July 1991 a new Industrial Policy Statement abolished licensing except for 16 industries. The numbers of industries reserved for the public sector were reduced; automatic permission for foreign equity participation up to 51 per cent was granted for a number of high-tech, high-investment priority industries; there was significant trade liberalization in regard to capital and intermediate goods (though little change at this stage so far as consumer goods were concerned); there were financial reforms; and macroeconomic stabilization was achieved with devaluation of the exchange rate and reduction of the fiscal deficit.

Скачать книгу