Скачать книгу

over time brings about institutional change (Acemoglu et al. 2005). This helps to explain what we mean when we say that economic growth is subject to circular and cumulative causation. There is an important feedback relationship between the pattern of growth and its political drivers, but this also sets a path of change from which it is difficult to break away.

      An example of this from India is that policy decisions taken in the 1950s, the outcome of the relationships that then prevailed between political and economic elites, set the country on a course of industrial development that has favoured capital-intensive industry in spite of India’s apparent comparative advantage, given an abundance of cheap labour power, in labour-intensive industry. In 2017 Arvind Panagariya, then the outgoing Deputy Chairman of the Niti Aayog, the body set up in 2014 to replace the old Planning Commission, lamented what he referred to as the ‘Brahminical mind-set’ of India’s big business groups, because of their evident preference for capital-intensive sectors rather than for investing in labour-intensive manufacturing. But in his remarks Panagariya also referred to the significance of the reservations that were instituted early in the history of independent India, restricting the production of many basic consumer goods to small-scale industrial units, so keeping out the big companies: ‘We have not been able to shake out of these historical legacies. In a natural way, the future structure of the economy gets a bit driven by the current structure. And our current structure has been determined by … the old licence permit, small-scale reservation period’ (reported in The Hindu, 13 August 2017).

      Research shows, therefore, that institutions (which include regulations such as those restricting the production of a range of commodities to small industrial units, as well as, for example, those that define property rights) exert an important influence on patterns and rates of economic development. But we also have to recognize that there may be a big gap between what institutions lay down, and what actually happens. Pritchett and Werker, for instance, refer to the rules regarding the issue of a driving licence in Delhi. These state that everyone should take a driving test, but research showed that only 12 per cent of those who had employed a tout, an intermediary, ended up taking the test. The touts, for a ‘fee’, found ways around the rules. In practice, the two authors argue, ‘in a regime of weak capability for policy implementation – that is, weak capability … to enforce rules – the actual practice is “deals”, and there are ubiquitous and widespread deviations of actual practice from “rules”, that create winners and losers’ (2012: 39). Rules, if they are properly implemented, are impersonal, while the term ‘deal’ refers to actions that are the result of the characteristics or the actions of specific individuals, and that are ‘one-off’. They have no implications for future transactions between other individuals. Deals may be ‘open’ or ‘closed’. In the latter case the possibility of a deal depends upon the identities of those concerned; in the former they depend only upon the actions of the agents involved. And deals may be ‘ordered’ – they will be honoured once negotiated – or ‘disordered’, when there is no certainty that the arrangement will be delivered upon. We may surmise that a movement from disordered to ordered deals is likely to be conducive to growth – investors will be more likely, for example, to invest in the capital equipment that is crucial for growth but that involves a large sunk cost; and that a shift from closed to open deals may be conducive to sustained growth, because it implies movement away from cronyism and increased competition. But there is no necessary, linear movement from closed, disordered deals to open and ordered ones. It will depend upon the settlements made between economic and political elites.

      Joshi’s broad overview (2017: ch. 2) of the history of economic development of independent India, showing that it falls into two halves, with the break coming around 1980 (see table 2.1), reflects a common understanding – though some think that the break came a little earlier, in the late 1970s. Kotwal et al. (2011) confirm that between 1951 and 1979, average growth rates remained below 4 per cent, and they say that the departure from the trend line after 1980 is both clearly visible in the data, and demonstrated in econometric testing. If an adjustment is made, however, for the sharp decline in GDP that took place in 1979–80, then the break is seen to have occurred in 1975–76. What is also noteworthy is that the variance in the growth rate declined sharply: from 15.8 in the 1970s, to 4.6 in the 1980s, and to 1.5 in the 1990s.

      What seems to have underlain the improvement in TFP from the 1980s onwards – taking place especially in services (see Bosworth and Collins 2015, table 1) – was a sharp increase in private investment in equipment. This, in turn, appears

Скачать книгу