Скачать книгу

lead to a concept that is relevant in the context where the term normally is used. A definition of market value should be such that market value ‐ so defined ‐ will be of interest for potential buyers and sellers thinking about a future transaction, or for measuring the wealth of a company in the balance sheet.

      As there always are uncertainty about the price that is possible to fetch when selling a specific property at a specific point in time, the formulation ‘most probable price’ seems to be the best as this uncertainty then is clear. In IVSC (2019 , p. 18), ‘the estimated amount’ is also explained in terms of ‘the most probable price reasonably obtainable in the market’, even though it is not clear what ‘reasonably obtainable’ adds to the formulation.

      The next question is how ‘most probable’ should be interpreted in the context of property valuation. As discussed in Lind (1998 ), there are at least two definitions of probability, or two different ways of looking at the concept of probability.

      The first is the frequency interpretation of probability. In this interpretation, saying, for example, that the probability is 1/6 to get the number 3 when throwing a dice would simply mean that if the dice is thrown a large number of times, then the result would be a number 3 in 1/6 of the throws.

      This interpretation is, however, rather meaningless in a real estate valuation context as it is not practically possible to sell the same property a large number of times during a short period of time. Even in a rather homogenous market, there is a limited number of transactions. Defining the most probable price as the average of the observed prices would be the same as saying that the probability of getting a number 3 is not 1/6 because the frequency of getting number 3 differed from 1/6 in the first 10 throws. With a frequency interpretation of probability, it would therefore not be possible to present convincing evidence whether a certain price is the most probable or not.

      A second interpretation of probability is the logical interpretation, where probability measures the degree of confidence that is rationally justified by the available evidence. This interpretation seems very suitable in a property valuation context. When a valuer, for example, asserts that the value is 100, it would in this interpretation mean that given the available evidence it is more rational to believe in a price around 100 than to believe in a price around 90 or around 110. Controversies about the value of a specific property can also typically be seen as controversies about the interpretation of the relevant evidence. A valuation method is from this perspective a method to collect and analyse evidence in order to arrive at rational belief about what the price will be if the property is sold.

      The conclusion in this section is then that the formulation ‘most probable price’ is the best one and that it can be explained further by saying that it refers to the price for which there is the strongest arguments, or for which there is the strongest evidence.

      A special feature of the Appraisal Institute definition is that it refers to the price in ‘a competitive market’, while there is no such reference in the IVSC definition.

      Including such a condition would also create methodological problems. If market value is defined as the probable price on a competitive market and the current market is not so competitive, there is no observable evidence about the price on the competitive market. Observed prices could not be used directly to make inferences about the market value and that is a big problem as valuation should be based on observable evidence.

      The condition that parties had acted knowledgeably and prudently is clarified in the following way in IVSC (2019 , p. 19–20):

      presumed that both the willing buyer and the willing seller are reasonably informed about the nature and characteristics of the asset, its actual and potential uses, and the state of the market as the valuation date… . the prudent buyer or seller will act in accordance with the best market information available at the time.

      The second argument against including reference to prudent and knowledge actors is the same as the argument against including a reference to competitive markets. In reality, the prudence and knowledge differ between actors, between markets and over time, and the market value concept should be applicable independently of the characteristics of the actors on the market. Adding references to prudence and knowledge reduces the relevance of the market value so defined, especially when a valuation is done for transaction purposes.

      The conclusion would therefore be that the conditions about prudence and knowledgeability should not be included in the definition. The valuer should look at the current market as it is and should not have to evaluate whether the actors in this market are rational or not, given a certain interpretation of rationality. It should also be remembered that the market value definition refers to the most probable price, and if there now and then are (especially) stupid actors on the market – paying too much or selling to cheap compared to other transactions at the same time – those prices would simply not be rational to expect and should therefore not be given great weight when the market value is estimated. This means that the valuer might need to evaluate what lies behind certain transactions with deviating prices, but

Скачать книгу