Скачать книгу

to the rules-based TPP devised by the United States (pre-Trump) and its Asian friends.

      An even more complicated interaction is taking place with respect to Huawei and, more broadly, in the high-technology domain. The United States argues that Huawei, the world’s largest producer of network gear for phone companies and the no. 2 global smartphone brand, can be controlled by the Chinese government and thus poses unacceptable threats to its own national security and that of its allies. It has banned Huawei from government contracts, slapped export controls on sales of most US supplies (including key semiconductors) to the company, taken other legal actions against it, and urged its allies to adopt similar policies. Most Chinese view Huawei as a national treasure, and President Xi personally complained to President Trump on several occasions about its treatment by the United States.

      The reactions have been mixed. A few allies have agreed. Some have rejected the US overtures on the view that Huawei’s economic efficiencies are highly attractive and that no security intrusions have been demonstrated. Others have adopted a middle course, creating new review mechanisms or otherwise responding to the company’s bids on a case-by-case basis. Suspicions are widespread that the United States is using a security rationale to advance its desire to restrain China’s development (as it misused that rationale to justify tariffs on steel and aluminum, and potentially on automobiles).

      The security linkage, much more clearly than with the AIIB, further complicates the Huawei case. It gives the United States, with its much greater power and leadership in the security domain, more leverage than on the “purely economic” issues, especially with its close allies (as in NATO) and, since intelligence questions are a major part of the issue, even more so with its fellow “Five Eyes” members in that space (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, United Kingdom). Even here, however, it has been unable to win full support in the face of strong Chinese economic capability and political clout (and its own inability to present, at least publicly, a compelling case against the company).

      Though ostensibly addressing immediate concerns such as merchandise imbalances and level playing fields, the trade war is rooted in deeply systemic issues, none of which was addressed effectively in the Phase One agreement reached in January 2020. China’s widespread deployment of subsidies to SOEs and others, demands for technology transfers to obtain access to its markets, and theft of intellectual property all reflect its state-centric economic system and disdain for the rule of law – basic conflicts with the international regime and norms that have prevailed, albeit in highly imperfect form, for over half a century. They raise the quintessentially systemic issue of whether China’s “socialist market economy” and the traditional capitalist system of the West can coexist without constant conflict. This latest source of China – United States confrontation thus underlines the imperatives of both systemic reform and cooperation between the two superpowers to make such reforms happen. So does their multifaceted conflict over the coronavirus pandemic in 2020, which deepened the mistrust and confrontation engendered by the trade war.

      Several examples of effective systemic cooperation between China and the United States can also be observed. They both contributed to an effective resolution of the Asian financial crisis in 1997–8, the United States mainly through the IMF, and China by avoiding any devaluation of its own currency, which would have greatly intensified the contagion of the period. (They both rejected Japan’s proposal for an Asian Monetary Fund, killing an idea that could indeed have challenged the existing architecture but that has come back in modified form via the Chiangmai Initiative Multilateral supported by both China and Japan.)

      They adopted parallel fiscal and monetary stimulus measures in response to the global financial crisis a decade later, effectively rescuing the world economy. They largely resisted protectionist impulses, avoiding the extensive erosion of the global trading system that was widely feared. They consulted actively on containing the euro crisis. China and the United States collaborated to conclude the Paris Agreement on global warming in 2015 (subsequently repudiated by President Trump, but maintained by the rest of the world including China and rejoined by President Biden). Their Phase One agreement in early 2020 called at least a temporary truce in the trade war that was roiling the world economy.

      These cooperative episodes fall far short of an ongoing G-2 co-leadership of the global order, which the two countries explored during 2005–9 and will be addressed in chapter 9. They do, however, indicate the potential for such cooperation. They also reveal the willingness of China to exercise effective leadership, at least when the system on which it relies so heavily seems to be at risk.

      China never admitted liability but, at least partially in response to US pressure, let the RMB begin to rise gradually, while still intervening heavily to limit the pace of appreciation, in 2005 and in 2010–11 again after the global financial crisis. The RMB eventually climbed by 40 percent against the dollar with a subsequent decline in the external global surplus to about 1 percent of GDP (though with continued growth of its bilateral surplus with the United States). Manipulation ceased by 2014, and in fact gave way to sizable intervention to limit depreciation of the currency in 2015, and there was no repetition of the practice after that time. The semi-annual reports of the Treasury Department concluded that China was no longer manipulating and Secretary Mnuchin’s

Скачать книгу